Liquor ban: Is there a rational

After reading this excellent post on the liquor store regulation idea on Kiwiblog (which aggregates the thinking of a number of other blog authors posts on the issue are found ,,,), I’ve decided to do a little thinking out loud about the issue.

Now, to analyse what it going on we have to ask why we want to have tighter controls on liquor outlets in the first place. From what I can tell, liquor outlets aren’t the direct cause of harm – the consumption of alcohol is. As a result, these measures are based on the causal link: More liquor outlets -> more liquor consumption -> more crime.

For fun, lets take as given that more liquor consumption leads to more crime. We still need the prevalence of more liquor outlets to cause more liquor consumption for this story to float. How does this work?

Well the fact that there are more liquor outlets DOES NOT increase demand for alcohol. It does however reduce the transaction cost associated with buying alcohol. As a result, if we have more liquor outlets popping up around the place, we can expect more alcohol consumption in the areas where the outlets turn up – fair enough.

However, how do we calculate the transaction cost? Well, there is the cost of getting to the outlet (say the cost of driving there) but more importantly there is an opportunity cost associated with getting there and buying it – namely the cost of time.

As a result, if the government’s policy was to reduce the density of liquor outfits in a uniform fashion across the country, everyone would suffer a certain increase in the cost of grabbing any liquor solely from their opportunity cost of time. Now it would seem to me that people who are going to commit the sort of violent crime that this policy is reacting to (robbing liquor stores) would probably have a lower opportunity cost of time than the rest of society – implying that it will have less impact on their liquor consumption decisions in the first place.

If the policy instead focused on lowering the density of liquor stores in areas that are susceptible to this type of crime then we have to ask – what sort of reduction in liquor consumption would we see from this increase in costs. I suspect that the answer will be, a very small decrease.

This reminds me of back in the day when King Country was a “dry” area.  The liquor outlets in Kihikihi had a great time of it, as people would just travel north to get their alcohol, or would brew their own.  If full scale liquor bans struggled to prevent consumption back then, having to drive an extra couple of km’s to get booze now isn’t going to stop many people.

As a result, if the link between the number of liquor stores and the quantity of liquor consumption among the target group is very small, then this policy seems really quite pointless. The law offices of Todd Landgren supporting this statement.

Although Mrs Clark stated that:

New Zealand research, soon to be published, would show outlet density was associated with binge drinking and alcohol-related harm to young people, Miss Clark said.

the correlation between these two variables in recent times does not imply causation without a believable story behind it.

The existence of liquor outlets DOES NOT create demand for liquor – it can only influence the cost of getting liquor.  If we really want to reduce alcohol consumption as the result of an externality we should just tax it (although I realise this is far from a perfect solution, given the way the externality is created), rather than messing around regulations – or potentially we could do nothing at all, and realise that whatever we try to do will just make matters worse.

13 replies
  1. Eric Crampton
    Eric Crampton says:

    Here’s an argument for it that I do not support.

    Specify that there are certain fixed costs involved in setting up security systems. The larger the scale of the shoppe in question, the greater will be its cash on hand and so too the optimal security system. So long as the returns to scale in security systems outweigh the increased return to robbing larger outlets, it’s better to have fewer shoppes that have armed guards rather than lots of small shoppes with security cameras.

    Again, I do not think that the gains to security outweigh the costs of regulation inducing the shift to fewer larger shoppes, so I do not support this argument. But at least it’s a plausible one, unlike the ones I’ve heard from the govt thus far.

    Too bad Rodney Hide and Heather Roy couldn’t coordinate amongst themselves to make sure they weren’t both out of the House at the same time.

  2. Matt Nolan
    Matt Nolan says:

    “Again, I do not think that the gains to security outweigh the costs of regulation inducing the shift to fewer larger shoppes, so I do not support this argument”

    Furthermore, it implies that we should do away with small shops altogether, even if they are not selling alcohol 🙂

    I appreciate the thinking outside the squareness of it though – thats what it seems economists do best when trying to justify government policy 🙂

  3. Eric Crampton
    Eric Crampton says:

    My favourite example of the “thinking outside the square…when trying to justify govt policy”: I coedited a book with Cowen on market failure. I soon after got an email from somebody in UK Trade and Investment (variant on our MED) asking me what market failure argument could be used to support some initiative they’d come up with. I still use that example when I teach market failure and how we have to watch out for market failure arguments justifying policies ’cause often folks start from the policy and work backwards rather than the other way round.

  4. Matt Nolan
    Matt Nolan says:

    “cause often folks start from the policy and work backwards rather than the other way round”

    Too true – must be one of the joys of working as an economist in the public sector, good thing that we don’t 🙂

  5. Steve
    Steve says:

    Perhaps the thinking goes that reducing the number of stores, reduces the supply of liquor, the supply curve shifts to the left, reducing quantity supplied and increasing prices. However, if we assume that its the smaller stores that shut down as a result of a law change, we can probably assume that alot of the demand goes to those larger stores, who then, also with an increase in demand at that individual store, can take advantage of economies of scale moving the supply curve back to the right; sure security guards at larger stores may stop liquor stores being robbed but liquor is the cause of a lot more crime than just robbing liquor stores. This is a pretty poor argument because it doesn’t reduce the quantity at all, yet I expect this is the underlying assumption by the government rather than an assumption about a reduction in demand.

    I only have one other argument which I can’t say is particularly good, but I’m having trouble arguing against it.

    Perhaps this is about a long term strategy to influence our culture away from alcohol. I agree that the ones who pay the most for the proposed policy are the ones who enjoy only the occasional alcoholic beverage. Alcoholics and heavy drinkers probably don’t care about the slight increase in transaction costs so it doesn’t stop them from drinking. However, by reducing the number of stores, this may reduce the influence the alcohol industry has on low drinkers and young drinkers thereby reducing the number of people who move from the low drinker category into this heavy drinker category. i.e. in the long run there is a reduction in the demand curve; whereas in the short term there is only a material increase in transaction costs for those who don’t place a high value on personal drinking (perhaps those who percieve a high negative externality of heavy drinking – this is another discussion altogether but in short I kind of like the idea that those who see the need for change also pay the costs for implementing that change; and those who cause the negative externality to society pay the costs of duties etc).

    I guess this whole argument comes with an assumption that our heavy drinking culture in NZ comes from the high avaliability of alcohol – (This is prob more anthropology than economics but would be interesting to find out). I would assume that avaliability is probably only a small factor – prohibition, the 6 oclock swill etc, were all initiatives that reduced availability, yet I think haven’t reduced this drinking culture.

  6. Matt Nolan
    Matt Nolan says:

    Hi Steve, good points I’ll try to discuss them:

    “Perhaps the thinking goes that reducing the number of stores, reduces the supply of liquor, the supply curve shifts to the left, reducing quantity supplied and increasing prices”

    I had this thought as well. However, as you say supermarkets are unlikely to change liquor prices as a result of this legislation, and they are the price leaders in the market.

    “However, by reducing the number of stores, this may reduce the influence the alcohol industry has on low drinkers and young drinkers thereby reducing the number of people who move from the low drinker category into this heavy drinker category”

    Indeed, so this would fundamentally treat alcohol as an addictive or experience good where we have some sort of “over-lapping generations” type of thing going on.

    However, I’m not convinced that a small transaction cost such as having to drive up the road a little further would be sufficient to change the consumption of alcohol by young people.

    Furthermore, I can think of two ways that this may actually lead to worse drinking habits. Firstly, by restricting the number of liquor outlets you may effectively increase the demand for alcohol by young people by making it more “taboo”.

    Secondly, the transaction cost is on the initial purchase of alcohol – not the quantity you buy. As a result, this policy makes it optimal to buy more alcohol at once. Given that the amount you drink suffers from a time inconsistency problem (“I can have one more”) this effectively reduces peoples ability to buy less alcohol as a precommitment mechanism – leading to more binge drinking (speaking from far too much experience 🙂 ).

    Ultimately, as long as supermarkets continue to sell alcohol the increased transaction costs will be incredibly small and will not lead to any sort of improvement in our binge drinking culture.

    “I guess this whole argument comes with an assumption that our heavy drinking culture in NZ comes from the high avaliability of alcohol”

    That is partially true, there is a holistic type argument that states that the availability of alcohol will increase demand for it over time, as it becomes part of our social fabric. However, then we have to ask, will shutting down some small liquor stores heavily reduce availability? I’m not convinced it will.

  7. Steve
    Steve says:

    Hey that was great, I was having trouble agreeing with the argument in my head myself but I hadn’t found a specific reason.

    My thoughts were that prohibition, 6 oclock swill has had little effect (if not a negative effect) previously so this should be similar for a policy that reduces the number of stores but why? You’ve answered this with the taboo argument, and that consumers will buy more per transaction, increasing binge drinking (same as the 6 oclock swill; where drinkers consume more in the shorter time avaliable). Completely fleshed it out, Cheers.

  8. agnitio
    agnitio says:

    while I haven’t had time to read over all the comments, I can’t help but be reminded of a certain accounting firm that that to stop employees getting too drunk shortened the monthly partner’s shout drinks to an hour.

    This then became known as “the hour of power”, if you only have an hour to drink you make sure you get your money’s worth!

    Gotta love unintended consequences:)

  9. Steve
    Steve says:

    That’s the 6 o’clock swill. Years ago in NZ, pubs had to close at 6 pm so that fathers would go home and be with their families. Of course it meant drinking as much as possible between 5 and 6 and driving home drunk.

  10. Richard
    Richard says:

    I think it was Campbell Live where they had a typically sanctimonious sounding voice over pointing out three liquor outlets within a few hundred metres of each other in one part of Manukau. Are the foolish people of Manukau really going to drink more if there are three rather than one liquor stores in one place?

    The only argument you could make for more stores causing more drinking is if the cextra competition is driving down prices – then the obvious answer would be jacking up taxes rather than restricting the number of stores. Have we ever tried restricting the number of cigarette outlets?

  11. Matt Nolan
    Matt Nolan says:

    I like your comment Richard – I think that could make a great blog post on your 100 word blog 🙂 as it is clear and too the point (something I obviously can’t do 😉 )

    I also like the comparison with cigarettes – stating that both have externalities, why should we treat them differently.

  12. Eric Crampton
    Eric Crampton says:

    I did a quick lit search on alcohol availability and crime. There’s not much out there, but what there is does suggest a link. I don’t like how they handled endogeneity though. Gyimah-Brempong, 2001, “Alcohol availability and crime”, Southern Ec J. Uses census tract data to show that the elasticity of crime with respect to liquor outlets ranges from 0.25 to 1. But he argues that the OLS estimates are underestimates because of endogeneity and that the higher IV estimates are the right ones. I just don’t get that. If an underlying variable is causing both alcohol outlets and crime (and in the same direction), OLS ought to overestimate the effect ’cause it’s bundling in the effect of the underlying variable. So, for example, if poverty increased both # liquor outlets and crime, and we had numbers on liquor outlets but not poverty, then our liquor outlet coefficient would be biased upwards ’cause it’s also pulling in the effect of poverty. But he’s saying that OLS is downwards biased.

    He does make that rather reasonable point that the full cost of purchasing alcohol includes the transactions costs of getting it, and increased availability reduces those transactions costs.

    Know of anything better on trying to work out causality?

  13. Richard
    Richard says:

    Excellent idea – some easy content!

    With most people having access to private transport, even in the poorest parts of the community, I wonder whether fewer stores affects transaction costs that much. I suspect more small liquor outlets in any particular place suggests you’ve the type of customers that aren’t that worried about a wide selection fine wines and boutique beers.

Comments are closed.