Isn’t Economic History grand

The discussion about Milton Friedman going on at the moment is great fun – with a bunch of people discussing whether Friedman was Keynesian and what this even means.

It all starts with Krugman attacking Friedman’s obsession with monetary aggregates.

Then the absolutely spectacular Uneasy Money blog more broadly defending the idea that Friedman was just relying on IS/LM in drag.  (Although this is moderated in a follow up and then more context here).

This is used here to attack Friedman and defend Samuelson-Solow (paper).  Sounds similar to this.  But if this point on not estimating the Phillips Curve is correct the defense is hardly compelling IMO – authors have to be clear about how their work will be taken, and those graphs are misleading!  It is good to “condition” results, but we can tell from history that these conditions were largely ignored and that Samuelson and Solow appear to have not said much to disabuse this – this is very important (even if I think the critics were themselves excessive).

Scott Sumner comes out and says Friedman wasn’t Keynesian, wasn’t as ideologically straightjacketed as these two seem to be implying, and that the sticky price models used (implicitly?) by Monetarists and Keynesians were pre-Keynesian.

This all in turn mentions this paper from Brad Delong from 2000 which discusses how monetarism transformed into New Keynesian-ism (the view I’d previously been bobbling around with).

Update:  And then along comes Krugman again – although he appears a little dismissive of history before using it.  A statement I’m a touch surprised about.

If you want my view in all of this – you must think I know more than I actually do.  I am no help at all!

My working assumption is the following when on the internet (so not at all in academia – where I don’t know if school labels seem as useful) – so looking at these terms at the current point in time, and taking these groups as self-identified.  The key difference I expect to hear as being between New Keynesian and a myriad of the groups that will term themselves “Keynesian” schools is the assumption around the long-term neutrality of money.

The key difference I expect to hear between New Keynesian and the “New Classical” schools has to do with the identification of the efficacy of monetary policy in the current environment.

The key difference I expect to hear between New Keynesian and the “monetarist” schools is a hard one as far as I can tell I only see these arguments put up as straw-men (I don’t see or meet anyone who calls themselves an old-school monetarist) – and this is where debates around whether money is endogenous suddenly appear from (from what I can tell everyone thinks it is outside of full reserve banking 🙂 ). Note, I view “New Monetarist” and the “Market Monetarist” labels as essentially versions of people that call themselves New Classical and New Keynesian – just usually a bit more technical 🙂

And the key difference between New Keynesian and “Austrian” schools (and some other flavours of Keynesian schools)  relies on views of the aggregation of capital and the function of the time path of interest rates on the type and duration of the capital stock.  Sometimes these guys can go down the exogenous money supply root as well, but I’m not a fan of that bit.

There is undeniably much more to each argument (for example, I have no doubt that many self-avowed blogging [New] Keynesian’s would state that the Neo-Wicksellian interest rate is time varying and can be adjusted by shifts in government consumption and investment – but this point, and everything with it, is a lot for me to take in 🙂 ).  But as these are all valid points, it is an indication that macroeconomics cannot use (or does not have) data that can allow us to satisfactorily falsify any of these views (which, for all no-one wants to admit it, rely on a series of firm a priori assumptions).  Tis a broader version of this Lucas Critique criticism of DSGE models, but to ALL macroeconomic models whether “mainstream” or not.

Note:  I would indicate how important testability and empirical analysis is in this – the “long-term neutrality of money” assumption and the “trend stationarity” associated with developed economies have been tested repeatedly and have been shown to hold in many circumstances.  Given the dearth of data and conditional nature of these models, this is very encouraging – but of course it is not the be all to end all.

Sidenote:  And this reminded me of the first paper that really convinced me about active monetary policy (I didn’t find sticky prices compelling until I saw this – this made the idea of small micro failures having big macro impacts compelling to me) – and it also pointed to the idea that we don’t want to go “too far” from our SR eqm, or risk dropping into a pareto-inferior outcome.  I missed this paper 🙂 – this has been fun.

UpdateDavid Laidler also runs through some economic history of this period (ht Stephen Kinsella).  Note this reveiw of a book about Laidler (ht Mike Moffatt).

Update 2:  Another David Laidler piece, via this piece by Nick Rowe that I ran into.  That also links further into writing by Simon Wren-Lewis where he makes this pretty essential point:

At the time there were attempts being made to partially microfound Keynesian economics by looking at rationing regimes where either goods or labour markets did not clear. Leijonhufvud was critical of this, and the earlier, emphasis on wage and price rigidity as being at the heart of Keynesian economics, both in terms of an interpretation of Keynes but also as useful macroeconomics. What I also remember, but did not fully appreciate at the time, was a good deal of discussion of the importance of intertemporal coordination failures, in which people’s expectations about long-term interest rates differ from the marginal efficiency of capital.

Update 3:  More links.  Money Illusion, Money illusion, Nick Rowe, Tyler Cowen, Romer and Romer, Krugman, Krugman, Money Illusion. Uneasy Money.  A series of links at Economist’s View.

Update 4:  More links I have to add.  Stephen Williamson, and Roger Farmer including a paper I’d like to read. And Noah Smith. More at Economist’s View.

 

4 replies
    • Matt Nolan
      Matt Nolan says:

      That is a neat article, cheers. I found this interestnig:

      But, for economists who actively engage the public, it is hard to influence hearts and minds by qualifying one’s analysis and hedging one’s prescriptions. Better to
      assert one’s knowledge unequivocally, especially if past academic honors certify one’s claims of expertise. This is not an entirely bad approach if it results in sharper public debate.

      The dark side of such certitude, however, is the way it influences how these economists engage contrary opinions. How do you convince your passionate followers if other, equally credentialed, economists take the opposite view? All too often, the path to easy influence is to impugn the other side’s motives and methods, rather than recognizing and challenging an opposing argument’s points. Instead of fostering public dialogue and educating the public, the public is often left in the dark.And it discourages younger, less credentialed economists from entering the public discourse.

      I see this as a bit more dangerous again, as I note here:

      http://www.tvhe.co.nz/2013/06/20/on-economics-as-method/

      The easy “answer” is to exaggerate our faith in our own results – but this makes arguments vulnerable to things we know will go wrong, conditional conclusions will be wrong as we never define an entire system. Fundamentally, we can’t forecast, and reasonable economists will disagree on (at least) the basis of normative judgments, and if we exaggerate the strength of our results we just end up in a situation where a single failure can undermine a broader set of useful economic ideas and principles!

  1. rwaldmann
    rwaldmann says:

    Thanks for the link. Nice post. I am commenting only on the bit close to the begining where you link to me and Forder “to attack Friedman and defend Samuelson-Solow (paper). Sounds similar to this. ” Your critique may be a valid critique of my effort there to study the history of economic thought (which consisted of reading a Samuelson and Solow (1960) for the first time and I’m a 52 year old macroeconomist). However, there is much much more at the second link and generally in Forder working papers. He claims, with many citations, that “we can tell from history that these conditions were largely [not] ignored”. In one working paper, Forder considers, in particular Johnson’s CEA.

    I strongly suggest you read his working papers on the subject (I have read 3). I just click the link you have here for the url oxford.ac.uk etc then search for Forder at that site. They have dramatically changed my assessment of Friedman’s intellectual honesty (I always thought he was slippery but now have the impression that he came very close to simply lying). Of course even aside from the critique of the Phillips curve (which contained nothing new to Samuelson and Solow or, for that matter, Phillips) he was a great economist with many wonderful insights. But the 1968 critique seems to have stated the conventional wisdom at the time and to be anything but a scientific revolution.

    • Matt Nolan
      Matt Nolan says:

      Hey Robert,

      Cheers for the suggestion – I will do! My prior is always that no economist is perfect, but Friedman, Solow, and Samuelson did piles to improve the discipline – it will be interesting to get a bit more historic perspective. I remember reading a book from the early 1970s on monetary economics, and the entire thing was about expectations – it changed my perspective on the way economists used to think back then as well, and made it clearer that viewing the discipline as a “straight linear progression” isn’t very fair on many of the incredibly good historic thinkers.

      It was entertaining to see a whole lot of you smart guys debate economic concepts through the lens of what these authors were actually saying. Good fun!

Comments are closed.